Maggbury Pty Ltd v Hafele Australia Pty Ltd

[2001] HCA 70

(Judgment by: Callinan J)

Maggbury Pty Ltd
vHafele Australia Pty Ltd

Court:
High Court of Australia

Judges: Gleeson CJ
Gummow J
Kirby J
Hayne J

Callinan J

Subject References:
Contract
Confidential information
Contractual restraint upon use of 'Information'
Restraint expressed to be perpetual
Information disclosed in patent application
Proper construction of contract
Whether restraint to apply once information disclosed to public
Whether contract in restraint of trade
Restraint of trade
Contractual restraint upon use of information concerning invention
Whether confidentiality agreement constitutes an unenforceable contractual restriction on trade
Whether the restraint imposed is more than that required to protect the interests of the parties
Injunction
Confidentiality agreement between inventor and potential marketer
Substantial copying of invention found contrary to agreement
Whether injunction granted unacceptably wide
Whether injunction would involve excessive supervision by court
Permissible scope and duration of injunctive relief
'quality of confidence'

Hearing date:
Judgment date: 13 December 2001


Judgment by:
Callinan J

87 The facts, the material terms of the contracts, and the relevant parts of the reasons for judgment of the Court of Appeal of Queensland are stated in the judgment of Gleeson CJ, Gummow and Hayne JJ and need not be repeated.

88 For the appellants to succeed, they must establish three propositions: first, that the contractual restraints in the agreements applied even though the information had become publicly available as a result of their activities; secondly, that the doctrine of restraint of trade did not render those contractual restraints unenforceable; and, thirdly, that an injunction to prevent further use of the information was an appropriate remedy.

89 I respectfully agree with Gleeson CJ, Gummow and Hayne JJ that, on the proper construction of the contracts, the respondents were under an obligation not to use information provided to them by the appellants. There was nothing in terms, in the contracts, which excepted from that obligation information that may have passed into the public domain. And indeed, as Gleeson CJ, Gummow and Hayne JJ point out [65] , the appellants did not covenant that the information had a confidential character. The question, as posed by their Honours, is, therefore, whether the restraint of trade doctrine operates so as to free the respondents from the obligation of confidence which they covenanted to fulfil and for which consideration was given.

Restraint of trade doctrine

90 The doctrine of restraint of trade gives effect to the policy that "every man shall be at liberty to work for himself, and shall not be at liberty to deprive himself or the State of his labour, skill, or talent, by any contract that he enters into" [66] . The doctrine derives from a reaction to the guilds and royal monopolies of Tudor and Stuart England. The common law set its face against these from at least the beginning of the 17th century, treating them as nefarious [67] ; and the doctrine came to extend to other fetters upon an Englishman's liberty to trade [68] . However, in response to commercial realities, the law was forced to relax some of its opposition [69] . It exempted certain classes of restraints from the reach of the doctrine [70] ; and it abandoned the prohibition on voluntary, general restraints (which operated throughout the whole of the United Kingdom or beyond) [71] . But although the guilds and royal monopolies of England have long since been consigned to the history books, along with trial by ordeal and the Divine Right of Kings, the ancient distrust persists. It lies at the heart of the presumption that restraints are bad unless proved otherwise [72] . It also underpins the rule that any restraint that goes beyond what the courts consider to be reasonable in the interests of both parties must be struck down, even if there is no evidence of harm to the public [73] .

91 The doctrine continues to operate notwithstanding that after all these years no universal test as to the situations to which it will apply has emerged. In my opinion, the time is ripe for considering whether the doctrine should have any application, or a much more limited application, in modern times. For more than 25 years, businesses in this country to which federal legislative power can extend have been governed by the Trade Practices Act 1974 (Cth), which establishes a legislative regime to foster and protect competition. That regime is policed by the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission, a statutory body with very considerable powers, some of which reach well beyond those of the courts exercising their common law jurisdiction in applying the doctrine [74] . Parliament regularly adjusts the legislation in the light of community and business needs, and the importance of competition for the economy [75] . That this is so should be taken into account in formulating and applying any contemporary doctrine of restraint of trade [76] .

92 It is also important to remember that the restraint of trade doctrine may inhibit, indeed even strangle, free trade rather than facilitate it. Lord Pearce made the point eloquently in Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Harper's Garage (Stourport) Ltd [77] :

"Undue interference [with contracts], though imposed on the ground of promoting freedom of trade, may in the result hamper and restrict the honest trader and, on a wider view, injure trade more than it helps it. If a man wishes to tie himself for his own good commercial reasons to a particular supplier or customer it may be no kindness to him to subject his contract to the arbitrary rule that the courts will always reserve to him a right to go back on his bargain if the court thinks fit. For such a reservation prevents the honest man from getting full value for the tie which he intends, in spite of any reservation imposed by the courts, to honour. And it may enable a less honest man to keep the fruits of a bargain from which he afterwards resiles."

These words were spoken in relation to the question of the reasonableness of restraints. In my opinion, however, they can equally be applied to the entire basis of the doctrine.

93 The law should seek to uphold bargains and enforce restraints other than those which are clearly and demonstrably against the public interest. In other words, a person who wants to break a restrictive covenant should be obliged to show that enforcement of it would substantially reduce competition within a marketplace, result in price fixing, or otherwise cause the public some real and discernible economic detriment of an anti-competitive nature. No less should be required to justify a unique interference with freedom of contract or the giving of a judicial imprimatur to what would otherwise be a flagrant breach of contract when one party decides that he or she has had enough of it. Both this case and the case of Peters (WA) Ltd v Petersville Ltd [78] are recent examples of a belated invocation of the doctrine to contracts which are freely negotiated by substantial arms' length parties fully advised by their own lawyers and which are largely performed by the time of that invocation [79] .

94 There is also an inherent contradiction in the idea of a notional reliance on the doctrine by a party seeking relief. People who enter into agreements intended to be legally binding cannot credibly be heard to say that they did so relying on, or conscious of, the existence of the doctrine of restraint of trade in its current form to relieve them of their obligations of performance.

95 There is a further difficulty. The doctrine of restraint of trade, as I earlier suggested, has not been clear in its application. A doctrine that provides no clear criteria for the ascertainment of the situations to which it applies can only be regarded with deep concern. The House of Lords in Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Harper's Garage (Stourport) Ltd suggested no fewer than three different tests for the identification of contracts or situations to which the doctrine might be applicable: the sterilisation of capacity test [80] ; the pre-existing freedom test [81] ; and the trading society test [82] . Other courts have preferred to exempt restraints from the doctrine on the basis of the "public interest" [83] . And although this Court has recently cast doubt on the sterilisation of capacity test [84] , it is not entirely clear what is to be the test in Australia.

96 In this case, the approach that I would prefer if unconstrained by authority would lead to a clear result. The respondents voluntarily entered into contracts with the appellants; armed with legal advice, they agreed to accept limits on the use they might make of information that the appellants provided. They should be held to that bargain unless they can demonstrate that the restraints cause the public significant economic harm of an anti-competitive nature. I find it difficult to see how that could be, particularly as they can continue to trade without relying on the disclosures by the appellants and they can use publicly available information as well as their own skills and experience. Any economic harm to the public would appear to be trivial or non-existent. It would follow that the doctrine of restraint of trade would have no application to the restraint.

97 I am, however, constrained by authority to apply the doctrine. Nonetheless, I would reach a different conclusion from that of the Court of Appeal. It is often said that the doctrine requires a person relying on the restraint to show that it is reasonable in the interests of the parties, and that it requires a person who alleges that the restraint is contrary to public policy to demonstrate that it is so [85] . However, it needs to be borne in mind that the requirement of reasonableness is based on, and intertwined with, public policy. As Lord Pearce explained in Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Harper's Garage (Stourport) Ltd [86] :

"Public policy, like other unruly horses, is apt to change its stance; and public policy is the ultimate basis of the courts' reluctance to enforce restraints. Although the decided cases are almost invariably based on unreasonableness between the parties, it is ultimately on the ground of public policy that the court will decline to enforce a restraint as being unreasonable between the parties. And a doctrine based on the general commercial good must always bear in mind the changing face of commerce. There is not, as some cases seem to suggest, a separation between what is reasonable on grounds of public policy and what is reasonable as between the parties. There is one broad question : is it in the interests of the community that this restraint should, as between the parties, be held to be reasonable and enforceable ?" (second emphasis added)

If the question is framed in these terms, I have no doubt that the restraint is enforceable. It is true that the restraint was unlimited in terms of time and place; but those considerations are not decisive. Courts do grant permanent injunctions from time to time [87] . And as to the absence of any geographical restraint, I point out that the market to which the parties were looking was an international one. A number of other factors, taken together, suggest that the restrictive covenant was reasonable. The parties were engaged in commercial dealings and the respondents were on an equal footing with the appellants, if not on a superior commercial footing to them [88] . They took their own legal advice. The covenant with the appellants that the respondents entered into simply forbade them from making use of information that was provided to them by the appellants: the restraint was designed to prevent the respondents from obtaining the benefit of the appellants' wall-mounted invention in ways that would harm the business of the appellants. The covenant left the respondents with their pre-existing freedom to trade, and did not otherwise interfere with their business [89] . It could not be said to injure the public by stifling competition. Indeed, as one court has suggested, striking down such restraints might have adverse consequences on trade [90] :

"The owners of new and unpatented products would hesitate before transmitting the information and making the disclosures essential to bring about meaningful negotiations."

All these considerations, in my view, lead to the conclusion that the restraint went no further than was necessary in the interests of both parties and offended no public interest. Even on the current law of restraint of trade, the covenant can and should be given effect.

Public disclosure

98 Something further need be said about the matter of public disclosure upon which the Court of Appeal relied as a factor telling against the utility, and therefore the availability, of an injunction. The appellants had, by the time of their first negotiations with the respondents, applied for both national and international patents. Priority dates of 14 July 1995 and 4 August 1995 applied to the former and were claimed in respect of the latter. Disclosure by any party after the priority date of the subject matter of the applications would not compromise the novelty, and the rights of the appellants to exploit the novelty, of the inventions, under the legislation. No patent has yet been granted. If it is granted, it is the appellants who would be entitled to bring proceedings with respect to infringements committed after the first publication (that is, on the opening of the application for public inspection as notified in the Australian Official Journal of Patents [91] ). It follows that nothing turns in this case upon the fact that, independently of the exposure of the applications to public inspection by operation of the Patents Act 1990 (Cth), a prototype and other matters may have been publicly disclosed. That disclosure would not have prejudiced the appellants' statutory rights of exploitation and protection on the grants of the applications. As to that, the respondents took their chances. They undertook, by covenant, irrespective of whether a patent might emerge or not, not to use or reveal what the appellants made available to them. Nothing, therefore, in my opinion, turns upon the public exhibition in which the appellants participated, of matter the subject of the agreements between the parties.

The injunction

99 There remains the question whether an injunction as granted at first instance could properly have been granted. The trial judge, Byrne J, granted an injunction restraining the respondents from manufacturing or distributing a particular wall-mounted ironing board. His Honour also restrained the respondents from manufacturing or distributing "any other wall mounted ironing board designed or manufactured using wholly or in part information derived directly or indirectly" from documents or prototypes supplied by the appellants to the respondents. The sources of information and the occasions on which information was provided to the respondents were listed in the order.

100 The Court of Appeal (de Jersey CJ, Pincus and Davies JJA) would have declined to issue an injunction preventing the respondents from using information derived from the appellants largely because the task of supervising it would have been "embarrassing". Their Honours explained:

"[I]f the evidence in an application for contempt shows that a particular feature in one of the [respondents'] models is identical with a feature in one of the various versions of [the appellants'] board referred to in the injunction, being a feature which has been publicly disclosed or is commonplace, the Court will have to delve into the process whereby that feature came to be in the [respondents'] board - from one of [the appellants'] versions, on the one hand, or from information published by [the appellants] or common knowledge, on the other.
There is much authority emphasising that an injunction restraining the use of confidential information should not be in such terms as to be likely to give rise to difficult or embarrassing questions when it is sought to prove breach ... Here the problem the Court would encounter would not be to discriminate between confidential and other information, that being the main difficulty in the sorts of cases to which we have referred. It would probably be to determine whether the presence of a feature which is in truth publicly known or commonplace is to be found in the [respondents'] board as a result of, for example, one of its employees having once looked at a drawing supplied by [the appellants]. It appears to us that that task could fairly be described as embarrassing, not least of all because it would seem to make little practical difference to [the appellants] whence the feature was derived."

101 I would make these observations about those passages.

102 This is a case in which the respondents, with their eyes open, agreed to abide by a restraint that prevented them from using information even though the appellants might disclose that information to the public. The restraint is in substance and in form a negative covenant. It is established that, in such cases, the correct approach is to grant the injunction unless there are good reasons to the contrary. Yeldham J in Broken Hill Proprietary Co Ltd v Hapag-Lloyd Aktiengesellschaft expressed the matter in terms with which I would agree [92] :

"[I]t is plain, in my opinion, from a long series of cases of authority, that the breach of a negative covenant, especially where private rights only are concerned, 'constitutes a strong foundation for relief by way of injunction' [93] . In J C Williamson Ltd v Lukey and Mulholland [94] Dixon J said: 'If ... a clear legal duty is imposed by contract to refrain from some act, then, prima facie, an injunction should go to restrain the doing of that act.'"

103 The Court of Appeal did not start from the view that, prima facie, an injunction should be granted. Instead, it stated that the injunction preventing the respondents from using information derived from the appellants should be refused because it would be embarrassing. That was not, with respect, an appropriate starting point.

104 In any event, in my opinion, the difficulties identified by the Court of Appeal are overstated. It is true that such lack of certainty as exists for the respondents is an important consideration that may warrant a refusal of an injunction [95] . However, much will depend on the actual situation. Excessively narrow formalism in framing the injunction may wreak its own injustice. As Meagher, Gummow and Lehane say [96] :

"In some cases, the practicalities of the facts may make it impossible to frame an injunction in anything but the most general terms; and, in any event, the danger of an order couched in overly particular terms is that it may leave the defendant at liberty to indulge in reprehensible conduct which is almost but not quite enjoined, without committing any contempt."

A more precise injunction than the trial judge granted in this case might have readily enabled the respondents to use information obtained from the appellants in violation of their agreement.

105 In Patrick Stevedores Operations No 2 Pty Ltd v Maritime Union of Australia [97] , the majority (Brennan CJ, Gaudron, McHugh, Gummow, Kirby and Hayne JJ; Callinan J dissenting) rejected a challenge to interim orders made by the Federal Court on the basis that the Court would be involved in "constant supervision" of conduct. From that case there can, I think, be discerned a judicial tendency to look to, and give effect to, the substantive merits of a party's case when injunctive relief is sought, even though to grant that relief may require further intervention by the court to refine the relief as the situation develops. In rejecting the challenge in Patrick Stevedores , their Honours pointed out that courts were "well accustomed to the exercise of supervisory jurisdiction upon applications by trustees, receivers, provisional liquidators and others with the responsibility for the conduct of administrations" [98] . They added that that case was not, as I do not think this one to be, a case in which a court "could never be sure that it was in a position to enforce its order without injustice" [99] .

106 Furthermore, I do not think that any potential for embarrassment for want of certainty here is any greater than in cases in which, for example, courts have restrained defendants from using confidential information or know-how. Courts have long recognised that the boundary between know-how and personal skills or experience can be hard to draw [100] . But that has not prevented them from holding, repeatedly, that covenants not to disclose confidential information or know-how will be enforced if they are reasonable [101] . It seems to me that the enforcement of the injunction granted by the trial judge here would impose no greater demands than the enforcement of injunctions in such cases.

107 The trial judge therefore had a proper basis for a grant of the injunction in the form that his Honour did. He found clear breaches of the agreements. He found that damages would be difficult to quantify. He also found that the distribution of the respondents' completed product was "likely to have a special impact". These were ample grounds for Byrne J to exercise his discretion to grant an injunction.

108 I would therefore allow the appeal, restore the judgment and orders of the trial judge, and order that the respondents pay the appellants' costs in this Court and the costs of the appeal to the Court of Appeal.

cf Welch Perrin & Co Pty Ltd v Worrel (1961) 106 CLR 588 at 611.

Investors Compensation Scheme Ltd v West Bromwich Building Society [1998] 1 WLR 896 at 912; [1998] 1 All ER 98 at 114. See also the remarks of Mason J in Codelfa Construction Pty Ltd v State Rail Authority of NSW (1982) 149 CLR 337 at 350-352, and of Lord Bingham of Cornhill in Bank of Credit and Commerce International SA v Ali [2001] 2 WLR 735 at 739; [2001] 1 All ER 961 at 965.

cf Bank of Credit and Commerce International SA v Ali [2001] 2 WLR 735 at 762 per Lord Clyde; [2001] 1 All ER 961 at 987.

(1991) 22 NSWLR 317. See also Heydon, The Restraint of Trade Doctrine, 2nd ed (1999) at 233-236.

cf Wright v Gasweld Pty Ltd (1991) 22 NSWLR 317 at 326-327, 329, 338.

Maggbury Pty Ltd v Hafele Aust Pty Ltd [2000] QCA 172.

Antaios Compania Naviera SA v Salen Rederierna AB [1985] AC 191 at 201.

Investors Compensation Scheme Ltd v West Bromwich Building Society [1998] 1 WLR 896 at 913 per Lord Hoffmann; [1998] 1 All ER 98 at 115.

[1978] 1 WLR 1387; [1978] 3 All ER 769.

Earlier authorities are noted by Menzies J and Windeyer J in Amalgamated Television Services Pty Ltd v Television Corporation Ltd (1969) 123 CLR 648 at 654, 655 and discussed in Carnegie, "Terminability of Contracts of Unspecified Duration", (1969) 85 Law Quarterly Review 392.

[2000] 1 All ER (Comm) 166.

128 F 2d 632 (1942).

128 F 2d 632 at 637 (1942).

172 F 2d 150 (1949).

172 F 2d 150 at 156 (1949).

[1964] 1 WLR 109 (n); [1963] 3 All ER 416; [1963] RPC 41.

[1965] 1 WLR 1293 at 1314-1315; [1964] 3 All ER 289 at 298-299.

[1965] 1 WLR 1293 at 1314; [1964] 3 All ER 289 at 298.

[1965] 1 WLR 1293 at 1315; [1964] 3 All ER 289 at 299.

[1965] 1 WLR 1293 at 1315; [1964] 3 All ER 289 at 299.

[1964] 1 WLR 109 at 111; [1963] 3 All ER 416 at 418; [1963] RPC 41 at 43.

[1965] 1 WLR 1293 at 1316; [1964] 3 All ER 289 at 299.

Concut Pty Ltd v Worrell (2000) 75 ALJR 312 at 317-318 [26]; 176 ALR 693 at 700-701.

[1990] 1 AC 109 at 285.

[1990] 1 AC 109 at 285.

cf United States Surgical Corporation v Hospital Products International Pty Ltd [1983] 2 NSWLR 157 at 228-233 (revd on other grounds (1984) 156 CLR 41).

Picard v United Aircraft Corporation 128 F 2d 632 at 637 (1942).

Conmar Products Corporation v Universal Slide Fastener Co 172 F 2d 150 at 156 (1949).

(1996) 186 CLR 71.

See the judgments of Brennan CJ (1996) 186 CLR 71 at 80-82, Dawson and Toohey JJ at 88-90, Gaudron and McHugh JJ at 101-102, Gummow J at 126-129.

(2001) 75 ALJR 1385; 181 ALR 337.

[1968] AC 269 at 298, 306-309, 316-317.

[1968] AC 269 at 328-329.

[1968] AC 269 at 335.

From a judgment of the Court of Appeal of the Supreme Court of Queensland: Maggbury Pty Ltd v Hafele Australia Pty Ltd [2000] QCA 172.

There were two such agreements and two Hafele companies (the respondents to the appeal) as explained in the reasons of Gleeson CJ, Gummow and Hayne JJ at [1], [13] ("the joint reasons"). For the purpose of my analysis differentiation between them will, for the most part, be unnecessary. Otherwise they are referred to as "Hafele Australia" and "Hafele Germany".

Joint reasons at [53].

Reasons of Callinan J at [89].

Clause 11 is set out in the joint reasons at [21].

The relevant subclauses of cl 5 are set out in the joint reasons at [21].

Reasons of Callinan J at [94].

As held by the primary judge: Maggbury Pty Ltd v Hafele Australia Pty Ltd unreported, Supreme Court of Queensland, 22 January 1999 at 25 per Byrne J.

The "Robinhood Ironing Centre", which featured a foldaway ironing board inside a box mounted on a wall or in between studs, without a carousel, retailed at $250-$330, whereas the potential for the appellants' version was to retail at $150.

Bacchus Marsh Concentrated Milk Co Ltd (in Liq) v Joseph Nathan & Co Ltd (1919) 26 CLR 410 at 440 per Isaacs J; Peters (WA) Ltd v Petersville Ltd (2001) 75 ALJR 1385 at 1394 [37]; 181 ALR 337 at 348.

Peters American Delicacy Co Ltd v Patricia's Chocolates and Candies Pty Ltd (1947) 77 CLR 574 at 590 per Dixon J.

Peters (WA) Ltd v Petersville Ltd (2001) 75 ALJR 1385 at 1392 [29]-[32]; 181 ALR 337 at 346.

Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Harper's Garage (Stourport) Ltd [1968] AC 269 at 324 per Lord Pearce.

Amoco Australia Pty Ltd v Rocca Bros Motor Engineering Co Pty Ltd (1973) 133 CLR 288 at 307; affd on other issues by the Privy Council: (1975) 133 CLR 331; [1975] AC 561.

Wright v Gasweld Pty Ltd (1991) 22 NSWLR 317; cf Triplex Safety Glass Co v Scorah [1938] Ch 211 at 216-217; Lindner v Murdock's Garage (1950) 83 CLR 628 at 640.

Howard F Hudson Pty Ltd v Ronayne (1972) 126 CLR 449 at 453 citing Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Harper's Garage (Stourport) Ltd [1968] AC 269 at 331; Adamson v New South Wales Rugby League Ltd (1991) 31 FCR 242 at 292 per Gummow J.

Biodynamic Technologies Inc v Chattanooga Corp 644 F Supp 607 at 611 (1986).

Reasons of Callinan J at [99]-[107].

[2000] QCA 172 at [22], [32]-[34], [36].

eg Mikasa (NSW) Pty Ltd v Festival Stores (1972) 127 CLR 617 at 651; Cardile v LED Builders Pty Ltd (1999) 198 CLR 380 at 396 [32]; Spry, Equitable Remedies, 6th ed (2001) at 4-18.

eg Broken Hill Proprietary Co Ltd v Hapag-Lloyd Aktiengesellschaft [1980] 2 NSWLR 572 at 581; Meagher, Gummow and Lehane, Equity: Doctrines and Remedies, 3rd ed (1992) at 619-620 [21 100]: see reasons of Callinan J at [102]-[104].

eg Queensland Co-operative Milling Association v Pamag Pty Ltd (1973) 133 CLR 260.

[2000] QCA 172 at [1], [8], [12].

British Franco Electric Pty Ltd v Dowling Plastics Pty Ltd [1981] 1 NSWLR 448 at 451.

Dean, The Law of Trade Secrets, (1990) at 305-307.

Byrne J found that distribution of the respondents' board would have a "special [adverse] impact" on the appellants: Maggbury Pty Ltd v Hafele Australia Pty Ltd unreported, Supreme Court of Queensland, 22 January 1999 at 29.

Maggbury Pty Ltd v Hafele Australia Pty Ltd unreported, Supreme Court of Queensland, 22 January 1999 at 21 per Byrne J.

Reasons of Callinan J at [103].

(1998) 195 CLR 1.

Set out in the joint reasons at [19].

Reasons of Gleeson CJ, Gummow and Hayne JJ at [51].

Herbert Morris Ltd v Saxelby [1916] 1 AC 688 at 701.

See The Ipswich Tailors' Case (1614) 11 Co Rep 53a at 53b [77 ER 1218 at 1219]:"[A]t the common law, no man could be prohibited from working in any lawful trade, for the law abhors idleness, the mother of all evil ... and especially in young men, who ought in their youth, (which is their seed time) to learn lawful sciences and trades, which are profitable to the commonwealth, and whereof they might reap the fruit in their old age, for idle in youth, poor in age; and therefore the common law abhors all monopolies, which prohibit any from working in any lawful trade".

See Sanderson, Restraint of Trade in English Law, (1926) at 19; Anson's Law of Contract, 27th ed (1998) at 360; Heydon, The Restraint of Trade Doctrine, 2nd ed (1999) at 3-13.

Meltz, The Common Law Doctrine of Restraint of Trade in Australia, (1995) at 16; Treitel, The Law of Contract, 10th ed (1999) at 415-416.

Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Harper's Garage (Stourport) Ltd [1968] AC 269 at 333-335 per Lord Wilberforce.

Nordenfelt v Maxim Nordenfelt Guns and Ammunition Co [1894] AC 535; Heydon, The Restraint of Trade Doctrine, 2nd ed (1999) at 16-19.

Sanderson, Restraint of Trade in English Law, (1926) at 24 traces the modern presumption against restraints of trade to Mitchel v Reynolds (1711) 1 P Wms 181 [24 ER 347].

The test of reasonableness between the parties has considerable difficulties. The test requires judges to substitute their own views for the decisions of businessmen and women, thereby overturning the arrangements on which the latter have based their affairs. It asks the courts to engage in a delicate exercise: they must not inquire into the adequacy of consideration or the fairness of the contract, but they can take account of the quantum of consideration to determine if a covenant is reasonable. The test also leaves undefined in what circumstances the "public interest" should strike down restraints that surmount the hurdle of reasonableness.

For instance, under s 80(1A) of the Trade Practices Act, the Commission alone can seek an injunction to prevent an acquisition which would have the effect of substantially lessening competition. It also has the power under s 88 to make authorisations excepting contracts and arrangements from s 45 and other provisions relating to restrictive trade practices.

Peters (WA) Ltd v Petersville Ltd (2001) 75 ALJR 1385 at 1392 [28], 1392-1393 [33]; 181 ALR 337 at 345, 347; Australian Capital Territory v Munday (2000) 99 FCR 72 at 92. It is worth adding that the relations between employees and employers, and indeed between principals and independent contractors in some matters and circumstances, are closely regulated by statute and the common law: see Workplace Relations Act 1996 (Cth); Stevens v Brodribb Sawmilling Co Pty Ltd (1986) 160 CLR 16; Hollis v Vabu Pty Ltd (2001) 75 ALJR 1356; 181 ALR 263.

Peters (WA) Ltd v Petersville Ltd (2001) 75 ALJR 1385 at 1392 [28], 1392-1393 [33]; 181 ALR 337 at 345, 347. See also Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Harper's Garage (Stourport) Ltd [1968] AC 269 at 327-328: "One of the mischiefs at which the doctrine was aimed originally was the mischief of monopolies. But this was dealt with by legislation and the executive has from time to time taken efficient steps to prevent it."

[1968] AC 269 at 323.

(2001) 75 ALJR 1385; 181 ALR 337.

See also Australian Capital Territory v Munday (2000) 99 FCR 72 at 92 per Heerey J: "When one party does seek to invoke the doctrine it will usually not be for any lofty motives of public interest. It has not escaped the notice of courts that sometimes parties of relatively equal bargaining strength freely enter into a contract but later one finds a more attractive proposition elsewhere and seeks to be released".

[1968] AC 269 at 328-329 per Lord Pearce.

[1968] AC 269 at 298 per Lord Reid, 309 per Lord Morris of Borth-y-Gest, 316 per Lord Hodson.

[1968] AC 269 at 332-335 per Lord Wilberforce.

Panayiotou v Sony Music Entertainment (UK) Ltd [1994] Trading Law Reports 532.

Peters (WA) Ltd v Petersville Ltd (2001) 75 ALJR 1385 at 1393-1394 [34]-[38]; 181 ALR 337 at 347-348. This Court, while noting criticisms of the pre-existing freedom test, made it clear that it was unnecessary to consider that matter further: see (2001) 75 ALJR 1385 at 1390-1391 [22]; 181 ALR 337 at 344.

Herbert Morris Ltd v Saxelby [1916] 1 AC 688 at 700; Amoco Australia Pty Ltd v Rocca Bros Motor Engineering Co Pty Ltd (1973) 133 CLR 288 at 307 per Walsh J, 316 per Gibbs J.

[1968] AC 269 at 324. See also Walsh J in Amoco Australia Pty Ltd v Rocca Bros Motor Engineering Co Pty Ltd (1973) 133 CLR 288 at 307.

See Heydon, The Restraint of Trade Doctrine, 2nd ed (1999) at 131-132 for a discussion of cases in which lifelong restraints were held to be good.

North Western Salt Co Ltd v Electrolytic Alkali Co Ltd [1914] AC 461 at 471 per Viscount Haldane LC; English Hop Growers v Dering [1928] 2 KB 174 at 181 per Scrutton LJ; Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Harper's Garage (Stourport) Ltd [1968] AC 269 at 300 per Lord Reid, 320 per Lord Hodson, 324 per Lord Pearce; Amoco Australia Pty Ltd v Rocca Bros Motor Engineering Co Pty Ltd (1973) 133 CLR 288 at 316 per Gibbs J.

Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Harper's Garage (Stourport) Ltd [1968] AC 269 at 298 per Lord Reid, 309 per Lord Morris of Borth-y-Gest, 316-317 per Lord Hodson. While these comments are directed to the scope of the restraint of trade doctrine, I can see no reason why keeping intact a pre-existing freedom should not factor in the reasonableness of the restraint.

Biodynamic Technologies Inc v Chattanooga Corporation 644 F Supp 607 at 611 (1986).

Patents Act 1990 (Cth), ss 90(b), 92(3).

[1980] 2 NSWLR 572 at 581-582.

Dalgety Wine Estates Pty Ltd v Rizzon (1979) 141 CLR 552 at 576 per Mason J.

(1931) 45 CLR 282 at 299.

Redland Bricks Ltd v Morris [1970] AC 652 at 666 per Lord Upjohn. See also Electronic Applications (Commercial) Ltd v Toubkin [1962] RPC 225; Suhner & Co AG v Transradio Ltd [1967] RPC 329.

Meagher, Gummow and Lehane, Equity: Doctrines and Remedies, 3rd ed (1992) at [21 100]. See also Spry, The Principles of Equitable Remedies, 4th ed (1990) at 366.

(1998) 195 CLR 1.

(1998) 195 CLR 1 at 47 per Brennan CJ, McHugh, Gummow, Kirby and Hayne JJ.

(1998) 195 CLR 1 at 47.

Littlewoods Organisation Ltd v Harris [1977] 1 WLR 1472 at 1479 per Lord Denning MR; [1978] 1 All ER 1026 at 1033. See also Heydon, The Restraint of Trade Doctrine, 2nd ed (1999) at 87-91.

Herbert Morris Ltd v Saxelby [1916] 1 AC 688 at 704 per Lord Atkinson, 709 per Lord Parker of Waddington; Printers & Finishers Ltd v Holloway [1965] 1 WLR 1 at 6 per Cross J; [1964] 3 All ER 731 at 736.